Disentangling Economic Thinking - YouTube

Channel: unknown

[0]
david colander and richard holt and i
[2]
have a series of several books and a
[5]
whole bunch of papers and we're still
[6]
doing these things studying kind of
[8]
where is economics going and and what's
[11]
the nature of economics and some of this
[13]
work has created some backlash i'm
[16]
barclay rosser or jay barclay rosser jr
[18]
and i'm at james madison university i
[20]
headed to the journal of economic
[21]
behavior and organization for a decade
[24]
and i'm currently editing a new journal
[26]
the review of behavioral economics you
[27]
have sort of three terms if orthodox
[31]
mainstream and heterodox and to some
[34]
degree we were inspired by seeing being
[36]
unhappy with mostly heterodoxy
[38]
economists who would talk about
[40]
mainstream orthodoxy or mainstream
[42]
orthodox neoclassical economic lumping
[45]
these things together so it's like
[46]
heterodox versus this
[48]
homogeneous mainstream orthodox
[51]
and we sort of decided things a little
[53]
more complicated so we decided there's
[55]
sort of two aspects here so one is an
[56]
intellectual aspect
[58]
and one's a sociological aspect
[60]
orthodoxy is really an intellectual
[62]
category so this is when we think about
[65]
standard neoclassical economics
[68]
equilibrium and
[69]
individual maximizing and rationality
[72]
uh these are aspects of this sort of
[74]
chicago school will be the sort of
[76]
supreme of this but it's in much of the
[77]
rest of the profession as well
[79]
this is orthodoxy intellectual orthodoxy
[82]
mainstream though is really a
[83]
sociological category it's it's the
[85]
people who are in charge
[87]
now some of the people in charge are
[88]
orthodox but a lot of the people in
[90]
charge really don't uh support orthodox
[94]
ideas they're they're non-orthodox
[96]
intellectually but they're
[98]
somehow they're you know they're at mit
[100]
and they're at harvard and they're at
[102]
berkeley and stanford and these places
[103]
think about somebody like george ackel
[104]
often so so people are doing behavioral
[106]
economics or vernon smith or
[108]
experimental economics i mean so if
[109]
people are very respected and uh they're
[112]
leaders of the discipline but their
[113]
their ideas are not
[115]
they're not standard neoclassical
[117]
they're not orthodox um but they're very
[120]
influential um heterodoxy however
[123]
combines the both so it is both
[125]
intellectual and sociological so people
[128]
who are sort of self-styled heterodox
[130]
uh are both certainly intellectually
[132]
non-orthodox
[133]
but also sort of they're not and they're
[135]
not in charge they're sociologically
[137]
cast and and this has led to of course a
[139]
lot of unhappiness but i will also note
[141]
over time that some of the this whole
[142]
emergence of you might say this sort of
[145]
non-orthodox mainstream that that's
[147]
something that's happened over the last
[148]
couple of decades uh the sort of
[150]
emergence of these sort of alternative
[151]
ideas which we are very much encouraging
[154]
that's been more in the last couple of
[155]
decades and it's become more important
[157]
but i think a lot of a lot of heterodox
[159]
economists sort of
[161]
are unhappy with thinking about that
[163]
they prefer to kind of have this duality
[165]
between the
[167]
mainstream orthodox and the heterodox
[169]
and the world's more complicated if not
[171]
complex the standard neoclassical model
[174]
just usually assumes homogeneous agents
[176]
especially at least at the macro level
[177]
of course microeconomics has always had
[179]
individuals have their own preferences
[180]
but usually you don't have these sort of
[182]
interactions sort of people's
[184]
preferences are on what i'm consuming
[186]
and that's it
[187]
you don't really worry about what other
[188]
people are thinking or what other people
[190]
relate to so
[191]
these interactions allow for nonlinear
[193]
dynamics and feedbacks that don't happen
[196]
in standard models and complexity
[198]
economics is sort of a major
[201]
theme of my research that cuts through a
[202]
lot of different areas modern
[204]
econophysicists actually claim that it's
[206]
physicists doing economics but there are
[209]
also a lot of economists working with
[211]
some of these physicists and trying to
[212]
kind of get a middle ground i mean
[215]
there's a very long history of course of
[216]
physics influence on economics and
[218]
economic theory you can go back and paul
[221]
samuelson
[222]
many of his ideas that are very standard
[224]
were drawn from physics people like
[226]
philip murowski have written books about
[228]
this sort of thing but this is a newer
[230]
this is a newer set of ideas so one of
[233]
the big themes has to do with
[235]
probability distributions so let's say
[237]
in financial economics and also on
[239]
income distributions standard economists
[241]
think about gaussian normal
[243]
distributions
[244]
but we know
[245]
that wealth distributions and capital
[248]
income distributions and also financial
[251]
market return distributions these are
[252]
not unrelated issues i have what are
[254]
called power law distributions so they
[256]
have fat tails they have greater
[258]
extremes so you have great extremes of
[260]
wealth you have great extremes of
[262]
financial market outcomes going up and
[264]
down and with speculative bubbles and
[266]
bursts
[267]
and the counter physicists they are much
[269]
more willing to use these kinds of
[271]
distributions these kinds of models it's
[272]
really quite amazing you can pick up
[274]
graduate textbooks by like say john
[276]
cochran or somebody
[278]
very advanced graduate textbooks
[279]
hundreds of pages long and you will find
[281]
no mention of of of leptokurtotic or fat
[284]
tail distributions they're using these
[285]
gaussian normal distributions which
[287]
simply don't fit reality so the kind of
[289]
some of the kind of physicists are
[290]
coming in and saying
[291]
you know you need to look at facts you
[293]
need to be more scientific of course
[295]
some of the economists come back and say
[297]
well but you need some economic theory
[298]
you have no economic theory you're just
[300]
you know making things up here but again
[303]
the account of physics models also tend
[304]
to involve nonlinear feedbacks nonlinear
[307]
dynamics
[308]
there's a close link with sort of the
[309]
broader complexity literature a lot of
[311]
the some of the important economic
[313]
physicists like doing farmer who's at
[315]
the santa fe institute i used to be you
[316]
know they were originally coming out of
[318]
doing chaos theory and all kinds of
[319]
nonlinear dynamics and now
[321]
doing all kinds of econophysics uh
[323]
models and so on some behavioral
[324]
economics is
[326]
i mean it's getting more recognized and
[328]
we've had a couple of nobel prizes i
[329]
mean thaler just got the nobel prize and
[331]
we've had a few others but uh people are
[332]
taking it more seriously i mean i think
[334]
one of the things that this is one of
[335]
those areas where a lot of people
[337]
realize that you know the world really
[338]
is how do people actually behave in
[340]
economics
[341]
behavioral economics tells you because
[342]
behavioral economics is they don't
[344]
always follow what economic theory says
[345]
they don't follow you know the
[347]
neoclassical individual rationalistic
[350]
kinds of models we're back to this stuff
[351]
that
[352]
colander and and holt and i were talking
[355]
about so people behave in all sorts of
[358]
ways and you know it may or may not be
[360]
rational but you have to if you want to
[362]
understand how the economy works what's
[363]
going on you have to actually look at
[364]
how people behave and people do the
[366]
darndest things as the old television
[368]
show used to say